The pension reform of 2021 entailed an increase of the state pension for salaried and self-employed workers. We are at the dawn of another pension reform emphasizing the need of a 2nd pillar pension constitution. One could wonder what would be the ideal pension income, or rather how much would one need to continue living according to his/her pre-retirement economic situation? How will a 2nd pillar Defined Contribution (DC) pension plan influence the welfare situation of one worker?
We will not pretend to answer such a complex question but rather share some reflections on the topic. Our objective is to illustrate the different elements as well as situations that might influence how a DC pension plan could/should be designed.
As an introductory note, the pension system in Belgium is composed of various pillars: while the 1st pillar pension refers to the state pension, the 2nd pillar pension consists of occupational pension plans instituted by the employer or the sector of the workers. The 3rd and 4th pillars refer to individual pension solutions set in place by the worker him/herself.
Our analysis is focusing on the 2nd pillar pension and its implications for the individual worker and his/her employer rather than on the state pension system itself. We are indeed aiming to improve our understanding on the financial needs after retirement and how much to save during a working career to continue living under similar conditions.
The current idea is that a 2nd pension pillar foreseeing a premium equalling 3% of the salary would be sufficient to enable employees to save for after retirement. But how can this percentage be appropriate for each category of workers?
Given the changing economic context, we were curious to understand in more details the outcome of a couple of simulations.
The replacement ratio can be defined as the ratio between the 1st total retirement income and the last salary before retirement. In other words, if a worker would earn a gross salary of 2,500 EUR per month just before retiring, and would benefit from a total pension income of 2,000 EUR, its replacement ratio would be 80%.
For this article, we considered 3 illustrative profiles of employed workers with different monthly gross salaries. Each profile intends to represent a percentile of the worker population in Belgium (percentile 20, 50 and 90 for a person aged 25). Each starts his career at age 25, works at 100% and is expected to retire at the age of 67 (no pension bonus / malus will be considered). The initial salaries are respectively 2.300 EUR, 2.700 EUR and 3.700 EUR for our profile 1, 2 and 3. These salaries have been defined based on Statbel 2021 information, although mitigated by starting age and function. These 3 profiles intend to illustrate the situation of workers in Belgium, reflecting various career paths, specialties, and expertise. The life cycle of each profile has been designed to reflect a general behaviour.
The salaries, as well as other financial charges and revenues, will evolve with an annual inflation of 2% and an annual merit increase between 0.6% and 5% depending on their career path and age. For the projections until retirement age, the longevity of the profiles is modelled by the IABE prospective mortality tables 2020 which are generational tables. According to these tables, it is expected that in average a person born in 1999 will live until 91 years old if he/she is alive at the age 67, leading to a period of 24 years after retirement age.
During their active life, the 3 workers will rent or buy a house/flat, buy a car, have children and finance their studies, etc. Their annual saving is therefore defined as the remaining budget after covering all the charges: they are expected to save at the maximum 20% of their net income. The simulation grants a return of 2% net on the savings’ investments, which is rather conservative / prudent although rather consistent with an inflation rate limited to 2%.
After retirement, while some charges decrease, others increase, such as a retirement home or medical expenses. The workers are assumed to build up savings and rights during their working life which will afterwards finance the old age expenses. The initial costs of the assistance support (before projections) are based on the current market price of health insurance, retirement homes, medication costs, etc.
The simulations do not reflect any change in the income taxation, the system applicable at the moment of writing this article has been kept unchanged (December 2024). Some of the specific taxes or deductions are not reflected.
We can observe on the below graph that during the lifetime of the participant, the savings’ possibility (the green line) varies and decreases sharply as from age 80 which concurs with our assumption that one enters a retirement home or benefits from similar services. While the active career is rather an accumulation phase, the post-retirement period is more like a decumulation one. Note however that the moment of the actual decrease in the financial means depends mainly on the moment the worker’s neediness increases, triggering additional care.
Based on this lifecycle, we originally determined the necessary replacement ratio to extinct any savings at the time of the expected death.
However, we noted that this situation is not realistic as it requires an exact alignment of the needs and expenses. Any deviation in the payment pattern as well as other unpredictable situation (such as inflation raising, pandemic, serious illness and costly (medical) treatment, financial crisis, family unforeseen events, etc.), would lead to financial difficulty directly and precarious situation.
As, there is no possibility to face these events after retirement alone (if younger family members are asked to cover the unforeseen costs, that would directly impact their financial situation and consequently their financial stability), we defined a more down to earth situation, targeting for a single payment upon the death of the participant or to face unfortunate circumstances or financial difficulties. This lump sum is determined as approximately 6 months of the last income at the age of 91. :
Replacement ratio |
Savings upon 91: 6 monthly last income |
---|---|
Profile earning 2,300 EUR |
44.83% |
Profile earning 2,700 EUR |
58.15% |
Profile earning 3,700 EUR |
64.03% |
We note that the selected goal of achieving 6 times the last salary does not necessarily reflect the same behavior of the savings amount for each profile.
For the Profile 1, the projection results in a negative annual budget during the high dependency age (>80), decreasing the remaining amount at the moment of death.
This is not the case for the other 2 profiles.
The amounts imply a replacement ratio sufficient to cover the expected costs, resulting in a neutral or slightly positive annual budget. We understand that this slightly positive income is explained by the real estate investment generating a sufficient income to cover the costs before death.
To build up these income after retirement (replacement ratios), the worker will receive his/her state pension and possibly a 2nd pillar pension. The savings accumulated during the working period (if any) can be assimilated to 3rd/4th pillar savings. Any improvement of this rate could be reflected in the amount payable upon death of the profile.
Simulating the replacement ratio of the state pension for each profile, we can observe that the state pension represents between 49% and 34% of the last salary - :
Replacement ratio |
State pension |
---|---|
Profile earning 2,300 EUR |
49.02% |
Profile earning 2,700 EUR |
45.65% |
Profile earning 3,700 EUR |
33.95% |
As the state pension is calculated on a salary limited to a defined amount (pension ceiling), the higher the salary is, the lower the replacement ratio covered by the state pension will be.
Comparing with the state pension replacement ratio, our conclusion is that the state pension will not be sufficient to cover the needs of the 2nd and 3rd profiles while it would be around the equilibrium for the 1st one. This 1st profile represents the situation of a minority of the Belgian working population (below 20% of the working population would be in this situation).
Our initial projections here below consider a pension plan offering an annual retirement premium of 3% of the salary. These coverages provide a total replacement ratio between 38% and 54% depending on the profile (under a legal minimum rate of return of 2.5% and a cost on premium of 5%).
Total replacement ratio |
State pension & 2nd pillar DC pension plan of 3%
|
---|---|
Profile earning 2,300 EUR |
54.05% |
Profile earning 2,700 EUR |
50.33% |
Profile earning 3,700 EUR |
38.17% |
The replacement ratio necessary to overcome unpredicted situations is not reached for the last 2 profiles. To achieve the desired replacement ratios (or objectives), a pension plan would need to provide at least a retirement premium, payable over the whole working period, of:
|
Savings upon 91: 6 monthly last income
|
2nd pillar pension plan |
---|---|---|
Profile earning 2,300 EUR |
54.05% |
3.00% x Salary |
Profile earning 2,700 EUR |
58.15% |
8.01% x Salary |
Profile earning 3,700 EUR |
64.03% |
21.36% x Salary |
We conclude that a pension plan defining an annual premium of 3% of the salary will not be sufficient for the 2 last profiles simulated.
In addition, due to the complementary nature of the 2nd pillar pension system and considering the limited retirement replacement ratio the 1st pillar pension offers to highest earning profiles, selecting a pension plan defined as a flat rate percentage for all workers does not provide the same level of protection.
Note that this observation explains the rationale of the step rate pension plans, which define a premium as a percentage of the salary below and above a certain ceiling.
Profile earning |
2nd pillar pension plan
|
Replacement ratio using an investment return of 2.5% |
Replacement ratio using an investment return of 3.5% |
---|---|---|---|
2,300 EUR |
3.00% x Salary |
54.05% |
55.19% (+1.14%) |
2,700 EUR |
3.00% x Salary |
50.33% |
51.37% (+1.04%) |
3,700 EUR |
3.00% x Salary |
38.17% |
39.06% (+0.89%) |
This demonstrates the importance of the investment return as one of the key parameters of a pension plan. However, seeking additional return of the DC pension plan implies increasing the investment risk for the beneficiaries and/or the sponsoring company. While the sponsoring company will face the investment risk below the legal minimum rate of return, the individual will support the investment risk above that threshold. The actual exposure will depend on how that threshold is applied on the individual assets. Let’s not forget the long-term nature of the pension system, allowing to derisk an investment portfolio towards the end of the working career.
In conclusion, an universal DC pension plan fulfilling identical needs for all is impossible, the relative level of coverage will depend on the individual worker age and salary (profession). This was demonstrated by our projections and simulations.
Designing a DC plan by taking into consideration the state pension benefit would allow a certain tailoring based on the salary of the workers, in line with the 1st pillar design.
A minimum level of coverage would not be achieved with a DC plan defining a premium equalling 3% of the salary excepted for the workers receiving a salary far below the average Belgian salary.
Seeking additional return (on top of the legal minimum rate of return) could improve significantly the replacement ratio and allows some protection towards inflation.